Offline
Aside from history one of my strongest interests in life has been the study of economics (including the history of economics, of course, from the French physiocrats to today). I devoured at least twice Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations at around 16. Naturally, I studied modern (neoliberal) Economics in university.
Failure of Free Trade
I think most of us are old enough to recall the neoliberal economic heyday of the 90's, where free-trade would guarantee limitless growth and prosperity, if only Unions wouldn't be so greedy. Of course, as history showed, this was naive if not totally wrong-headed. With the 2008 financial catastrophe, neoliberal economists were seldom seen or heard on the airwaves. Only the most obnoxiously and blindly indoctrinated could muster the shamelessness to continue promoting it, repeating ad nauseam that if only we were fanatically faithful to neoliberal economic principles, then the magic of free markets would drive us into unimaginable prosperity. That we should abolish the minimum wage altogether, privatize our police and fire departments and even our military was effectively what they were arguing.
Apples and Oranges
There are many reasons why free trade and tariff reductions failed to result in wonderful growth, especially in the richer Western countries (and only partly in poorer trade partner nations). One reason was that neoliberal economic theory always assumed a kind of civilization and legal equality between any two potential trade nations. The fact that the USA, Canada and Mexico and Chine are wildly different countries with wildly different labor standards did not get taken into account. It was borderline illegal to compete with those countries on the same level in terms of labor and the only easy route to do so would have been to drop Western labor standards back to the 19th century and effectively destroy the middle class as the predominant demographic for working people in the West. We did get flooded with much cheaper goods; however, the markets for those same goods were simultaneously shrinking owing to layoffs and the jobs that replaced them (to the extent they even were) generated a radically lower income (the so-called "service sector"; otherwise known as McJobs).
Unemployment
That was the first problem. The second problem was unemployment. Neoliberal economics is very good at realizing the interplay between supply and demand. However, it apparently failed to realize the implication of this beyond "widgets" (basically any product or service) and apply it to the job market. Unemployment economically is any situation where workers are seeking wages to provide for themselves and/or their households. This includes people working in part-time jobs or jobs that fail to ultimately provide a wage necessary to sustain themselves, especially just qua worker/laborer. Increased unemployment puts downward pressures on wages and earnings and increases competition among workers. It also increases competition (and decreases wages/salaries) for higher positions or management positions especially if the lower-order positions either fail or only barely allow a worker/employee to provide for their needs. It's not hard to see the effects this will have. It generates a dog-eat-dog mentality in the workplace and destroys solidarity, lending itself to thinking in radical dichotomies. Hence the rise of late in socialistic solutions to our economic problems.
For-Profit Business only Accidentally Generates Employment
We have to bear in mind that the first order of business for any business is profit. The very nature of our economic system places strong pressure especially on non-governmental firms to minimize expenditures (indeed, ideally, have no expenditures or costs ---do not forget that point! selling nothing or something that costs nothing for everything is rewarded by the nature of our system). Wages and salaries are virtually always the greatest expense and cost of any firm. It stands out much more glaringly than material requisition and property procurement and maintenance does. This places strong pressure to avoid hiring except when necessary or to delay doing so for as long as possible. This is true with the sole exception of when hiring results in or is necessary for greater overall profitability. The only time the latter conditions are generally realized is during periods of rapid market increase and expansion (e.g., after WWII). But a stagnant, shrinking or otherwise dieing market does not translate into hiring by firms but rather more aggressive cost decreases to maintain or increase profitability: businesses flourish when markets flourish; businesses stagnate if markets stagnate.
Technical Progress
Firms of course seek to become more efficient and will often employ new techniques, technologies and specialists to reduce overall costs. As a consequence, there are generally layoffs as experience and knowledge is accumulated. This creates tension naturally. Firms are not actually saying that labor is being rendered obsolete (in fact, the value of labor as such normally rises in real terms (though this doesn't necessarily have to translate into increased purchasing power for labor generally). The layoffs, however, result in unemployment. A firm has effectively said this labor is better applied elsewhere; however, our system doesn't have a means of really translating that labor to another application especially in conditions where there already is high unemployment or a stagnate or shrinking market (which just shrank again). This is one reason for supporting unemployment insurance; it at least buys a period for workers/employees to seek another job without the market contracting as much as it otherwise would have.
Business Presumes Markets
In consideration of the above it becomes easier to see why it's not always going to be effective to have a singularly pro-business or pro-firm side economic recovery theory. Government can't forget that civilization, for starters, is not a given; but it is a necessary condition for free markets in any meaningful sense. There must be courts, law and order and contracts must be enforced, for example. Furthermore, profit-making is not in fact synonymous with wealth production (which is more properly economics); I will argue next that the greatest error of all today is, arguably, the equivocation of profit-making with wealth production, which can result in bubbles and actual wealth destruction (i.e., can even be or become radically anti-economical) as happened on an unheard of scale in 2008.
Last edited by Timocrates (3/19/2016 5:43 pm)
Offline
I support this thread, the philosophic treatment of economics, and the return of true political economy.
Offline
Thank you iwpoe, and I have come to the same conclusion myself. Economics has to be looked at philosophically otherwise it becomes skewed.
My next post will have to do with the equivocation between profit-making and wealth production but also allay concerns that I am advocating a mere consumerism or over-emphasizing consumption without the obvious need for production. I am calling this for now "Market-side economics" for wont of a better name for it. It will become clear in my next post, though (which might come as early as this evening or tonight but perhaps not for a day or two - we will see!), that it is the duty of the State to strive to make profit-making or the pursuit of profit as synonymous as possible with the production and distribution of real wealth. I will also argue that the State can and does at times have the duty to secure markets and guarantee them just as surely as it had an obligation to provide for the minimum necessary conditions for free markets.
Offline
Interesting post. Are you critical mostly of neoliberal policies? What is your opinion of neoclassical economics itself? I read an interesting work called Steve Keen's Debunking Economics. It and the post-Autistic/Heterodox economic movement have really made me question neoclassical economics.
Offline
"Post-Autistic" is accurate.
I'm a big reader of Keen, and I began to question modern economic orthodoxy both from the angle of the history of economic thought-
Read, for instance, The Worldly Philosophers by Robert Heilbroner or anything by Scumpater, compare it to what passes for "economics" for the educated public today, and tell me if something didn't go wrong.
-and from the angle of neo-Marxist and occasionally anarchist economic thought. See for instance
A Brief History of Neoliberalism by David Harvey
Debt: The First 5000 Years by David Graeber
Indeed, a basic education in the principals of business management as an MBA would learn them shows that something is wrong with modeling the economy in terms of equilibrium, since firms explicitly fight to be out of the kind of commodity hell that would best fit that kind of model.
Offline
Eons ago I actually was an anarchist. I never quite settled on a particular school of anarchism. I was a leftwing or anti-capitalist anarchist, though I didn't despise the anarcho-capitalists. I was most drawn to the mutualists and individualist anarchists, but I also had a lot of time for Prince Kropotkin. I didn't like the flirting with Marxism of many collectivist and communist anarchists. I have never seen the great attraction in Marx's thought. He seems very much overrated to me, both as an economist and a philosopher. I find it bemusing his thought has inspired so many movements. Although, I must say, his work on primitive accumulation and his business cycle theory are very insightful. But as far as nineteenth century radical economists go, I find Henry George to be far more interesting and profound.
I moved away from anarchism but became a radical decentralist, retaining some anarchist influences and also becoming influenced by the likes of E. F. Schumacher, Wilhelm Röpke, and Chesterbelloc. Although I'm a little less radical in some ways, I still am very decentralist.
I have found some little known economic thinkers to be amongst the most interesting - Ralph Borsodi, Silvio Gesell, Heinrich Pesch, H. J. Massingham, Lord Northbourne, Leopold Kohr, Ivan Illich, Kirkpatrick Sale, John Seymour. But one economic writer I would in particular recommend is Kevin Carson. His older work especially (these days he has gone a little too far into radical identity politics for my liking) will really make think again about our economic system. More work needs to be done (I have in mind to write an article or two on the subject), but I think his arguments for the complete reliance of corporate capitalism on constant and increasing state intervention throughout the whole system is largely accurate. This means that neoliberalism is not in any sense natural. The massive accumulation of capital it contains, concentrated in a minority of business and individuals, only comes about, so Carson tries to show, because the state constantly supports it. It is the state that makes things like large corporations, large production facilities, huge supply chains, and the like profitable. It is also the state whose increasing intervention staves off crises of overaccumulation, which I think Timocrates alludes to, that occur because capitalism requires the rich and corporations to try to accumulate more and more capital, and to invest more and more money, just to have their relative worth stay the same. As most capitalists don't want to use more than a small amount of their money for consumption and the rest of us don't have enough, there is not enough demand for a lot of he investment to be profitable, except that the state steps in with demand management (including welfare), expanding markets (colonialism, trade deals), guaranteed markets (for example, massive military spending), and ubiquitous subsidies and supports. This, of course, is the business cycle of Marx, and of Hobson and Keynes, but with a focus on the role of the state to alleviate it.
Offline
The point about the behavior of capitalists themselves is also cogent. My family coosted on a relatively mild amount of wealth accumulated over two generations from roughly 1875 to 1960 until very recently. That portion of it that was invested in securities certainly had some amount of economic value, but the amount of it that was captured in real estate was essentially withdrawn entirely from circulation, for a century in one case.
Everything about the situation the United States is in does not encourage job creation but rather encourages the creation of a patrician class. I don't know what prevents the total halt of wealth creation at present, since we have clearly over invested in the wealthy for the past half century or more.
Last edited by iwpoe (3/19/2016 9:37 pm)
Offline
Jeremy Taylor wrote:
Eons ago I actually was an anarchist. I never quite settled on a particular school of anarchism. I was a leftwing or anti-capitalist anarchist, though I didn't despise the anarcho-capitalists.
Well, as you might know, neoliberalism just is anarcho-capitalism. Neoliberal economics necessitates the privatization of government if its logic were correct. It's effectively feudalism but with the ignominy of the merely rich rather than at least the actually strong lording over others. The rich, worthless, spoiled brat rules: and that is about as close to an effective Anarch as you can get.
Offline
You could argue that (well, I suppose it is a little bit unfair to the anarcho-capitalist, as he means something else by the term). There is the question of the role of the state in neoliberalism. It has certainly been argued, by Carson amongst others, that neoliberalism doesn't really represent a lessening of the role of the state in the economy. All it really saw was the end of a sort of consensus between the state, business, and unions in the post-war period and subordination of unions and organised labour to business and the state, making sure more profits and power go to business. Priviatisation is more a matter of who gets the profits.
Of course, sometimes free-marketeers will say we don't have a proper free market when bad things are pointed out about our current system, but then go back to trying to claim all they think are its good points are due to the free market. This is dubious on many levels, not least because a good argument can be made that protectionism was important in the early development of many developed economics.
Offline
Jeremy Taylor wrote:
This, of course, is the business cycle of Marx, and of Hobson and Keynes, but with a focus on the role of the state to alleviate it.
This is the Marx I'm interested in. Joseph Schumpeter is perfectly good here also, but Marx's shining glory is his (inadequate but still groundbreaking) attention to history and his attention to what we might call system-dynamics in the economy. This is because of the influence on him by Hegel. I generally think that everything of interest in Marx was already better thought by Hegel, but Hegel never thematized economics in any big way, so I have to look to Marx for this.
All of Marx's materialist post-Comte pretensions are unfortunate, and I imagine that he would have been a better thinker if he'd been able to escape that movement.